This is the third in a series of six
fortnightly articles by Real Estate and Housing Developers Association
of Malaysia.
A LARGE part of the housing delivery process revolves around the
provision of infrastructure.
In most countries, this is undertaken by the government as part of
its mandate. However, as nations and economies progress and modernise,
the trend has been for governments to privatise the development and
provision of infrastructure to the private sector.
This approach is favoured as it is perceived that greater efficiency
and productivity can be achieved via the privatisation route.
In Malaysia, this has also been the path the nation has chosen. From
essential services such as electricity, water, sewerage, to solid waste
management and telecommunications, the modus operandi has been to
privatise these services.
Indeed, there has been notable success in this approach. We have seen
Malaysia grow phenomenally in the last couple of decades, thanks to the
participation of the private sector, which has brought much energy and
enterprise to the development of greenfield areas.
Yet, even as we extol the virtues and benefits of privatisation, we
should be mindful that there is a price to be paid. One sector that
feels the impact most directly is the housing development industry.
Housing developers are subject to various requirements to provide
infrastructure for roads and drainage, electricity and water supply,
sewage treatment facilities, and telecommunications services. The cost
for providing such infrastructure is imputed into the cost of the
housing development and embedded in the house price.
House buyers are in fact already paying, via developers, a host of
fees and charges to utilities service providers, towards development of
a built environment that is well complemented and equipped with the
necessary facilities for safe, healthy and comfortable living.
But increasingly, the pressure being exerted on developers to
shoulder more infrastructure works and to comply with higher standards
by the privatised utilities providers has become unbearable.
There are two trends in infrastructure funding – one is the growth of
levies and charges on new housing development to fund an ever-expanding
range of infrastructure and, second, a move to charge developers
up-front for infrastructure development as in capital contributions.
For example, some 10 years ago, when Indah Water Konsortium (IWK)
wanted to build central treatment plants for sewage treatment, it was
proposed that a capital contribution charge of 1.65% of the house price
be imposed on new developments.
On top of that, developers would still be required to build treatment
plants within their own developments in the interim. This would have
translated into substantial additional costs to house buyers of these
new projects (around RM2,500 for an average house priced at RM150,000).
Fortunately, after many rounds of representations and discussions, the
Government suspended the proposal.
A more recent example was the proposal to require developers to
provide infrastructure for telecommunications services in new housing
areas to help the nation leapfrog into the digital era. It was felt that
without such infrastructure, access to broadband and the nation’s IT
competitiveness would be greatly hampered.
Again, it was conveniently suggested that the responsibility for
additional external trunking infrastructure be borne by the developer.
Even though it is the house buyer who ends up picking up the additional
tab, the issue of fairness and equity must be considered.
Developers have argued that they are not against higher standards.
But such requirements must be justified and equitably imposed.
In a buoyant market, there may be more flexibility to absorb such
increased costs, but the ability to pass on these added costs may not
hold in less robust times. Even so, the principle of payment involved
here is quite unfair.
Purchasers of new homes are increasingly bearing the lion’s share of
the cost of funding community-wide urban infrastructure that is enjoyed
by all, something that was previously financed by state and local
governments and paid for by the broader tax-paying community.
Home owners in older localities have historically had this external
infrastructure provided by the Government, so it is rather unjust to
expect new generations of home buyers to have to pay when past
generations of home owners did not have to.
Part of the problem is that planning for infrastructure is typically
piecemeal and tends to be agency-based rather than from a government
master planned perspective. It is also a fact that there are no
consistent principles underpinning infrastructure charges in the various
states and by the various utilities service providers.
Consideration should also be given to rationalising local government
development contributions with the aim of reducing redundant payments.
There should also be accountability for proper and timely allocation of
funds raised for infrastructure provision.
There is an urgent need for rationalisation of policies and
requirements that cause undue financing impositions on the house buyer,
especially against the backdrop of private utilities companies reporting
higher profits.
Each charge or levy may seem small on its own, but taken together,
all these add up to adversely impact accessibility to home ownership.
All stakeholders involved in providing infrastructure and utilities
must work together to improve the efficiency in the delivery process
without unduly burdening the new house buyer.